Antoine Augustin Cournot
1801-1877
$$R'(p)=f(p)+pf'(p)$$
$$\pi=R(q)-C(q)$$
Alfred Marshall
1842-1924
Alfred Marshall
1842-1924
“But here we may read a lesson from the young trees of the forest as they struggle upwards through the benumbing shade of their older rivals. Many succumb on the way, and a few only survive; those few become stronger with every year...and at last in their turn they tower above their neighbours...but sooner or later age tells on them all. Though the taller ones have a better access to light and air than their rivals, they gradually lose vitality; and one after another they give place to others, which, though of less material strength, have on their side the vigour of youth,” (p.506 in Reader).
“When therefore we are considering the broad results which the growth of wealth and population exert on the economies of production...our conclusions [are] not very much affected by the fact that many of these economies depend directly on the size of the individual establishments engaged in the production, and that in almost every trade there is a constant rise and fall of large businesses, at any one moment some firms being in the ascending phase and others in the descending” (p.506 in Reader).
Alfred Marshall
1842-1924
“These results will be of great importance when we come to discuss the causes which govern the supply price of a commodity. We shall have to analyse carefully the normal cost of producing a commodity, relatively to a given aggregate volume of production; and for this purpose we shall have to study the expenses of a representative producer for that aggregate volume...our representative firm must be one which has had a fairly long life, and fair success, which is managed with normal ability, and which has normal access to the economies, external and internal, which belong to that aggregate volume of production...,” (p.507 in Reader).
“We cannot see this by looking at one or two firms taken at random: but we can see it fairly well by selecting, after a broad survey, a firm, whether in private or joint-stock management...that represents, to the best of our judgment, this particular average, (ibid).”
Alfred Marshall
1842-1924
“The element of time is a chief cause of those difficulties in economic investigations which make it necessary for man with his limited powers to go step by step...in breaking it up, he segregates those disturbing causes, whose wanderings happen to be inconvenient, for the time in a pound called Ceteris Paribus. The study of some group of tendencies is isolated by the assumption other things being equal: the existence of other tendencies is not denied, but their disturbing effect is neglected for a time. The more the issue is thus narrowed, the more exactly can it be handled: but also the less closely does it correspond to real life.,” (p.516 in Reader).
Marshall, Alfred, 1890, Principles of Economics
Alfred Marshall
1842-1924
“To go over the ground in another way. Market values are governed by the relation of demand to stocks actually in the market; with more or less reference to ‘future’ supplies...the current supply is in itself partly due to the action of producers in the past; and this action has been determined on as the result of a comparison of the prices which they expect to get for their goods with the expenses to which they will be put in producing them,” (pp.516-517 in Reader).
“For short periods people take the stock of appliances for production as practically fixed; and they are governed by their expectations of demand...in long periods they set themselves to adjust the flow of these appliances to their expectations of demand,” (pp.517 in Reader).
Marshall, Alfred, 1890, Principles of Economics
Alfred Marshall
1842-1924
“To sum up them as regards short periods. The supply of specialized skills and ability, of suitable machinery and other material capital, and of the appropriate industrial organization has not time to be fully adapted to demand; but the producers have to adjust their supply to the demand as best they can with the appliances already at their disposal...In long periods on the other hand all investments of capital and effort in providing the material plant and the organization of business, and in acquiring trade knowledge and specialized ability, have time to be adjusted to the incomes which are expected to be earned by them: and the estimates of those incomes therefore directly govern supply, and are the true long-period normal supply price of the commodities produced.” (pp.519-5207 in Reader)
Marshall, Alfred, 1890, Principles of Economics
Alfred Marshall
1842-1924
“Of course there is no hard and sharp line of division between ‘long’ and ‘short’ periods. Nature has drawn no such lines in th eeconomic conditions of actual life...”
“Four classes stand out. In each, price is governed by the relations between demand and supply.” (p.520 in Reader)
Marshall, Alfred, 1890, Principles of Economics
Market period
Supply is perfectly inelastic
Example: a farmers’ market, a farmer shows up with a fixed stock of goods to sell
Short-run: some factors of production treated as fixed
Supply of both firm and industry is determined by diminishing returns
Divide firm costs into fixed costs and variable costs (“prime costs”)
Supply of both firm and industry is determined by diminishing returns
Firms will operate at a loss in the short run if they can cover their variable costs
Firms will shut down production in short-run if they cannot cover their variable costs
Supply of both firm and industry is determined by diminishing returns
Firms will operate at a loss in the short run if they can cover their variable costs
Firms will shut down production in short-run if they cannot cover their variable costs
Firm’s supply curve is its marginal cost curve above the average variable cost curve
Firms can change all of their inputs (i.e. capital)
More resources will flow in if representative firm is profitable (entry)
Resources will flow out if representative firm is unprofitable (exit)
Marshall would not correctly derive long run (AC, MC, etc.) curves for firms, discovered in 1920s-1930s
Ricardo: land rents are price-determined (by demand), not price-determining (part of cost) (“rent is high because the price of corn is high”)
Mill & others: land does have opportunity cost, an upward-sloping supply curve
Alfred Marshall
1842-1924
Alfred Marshall
1842-1924
Also depends on analytical perspective
From the perspective of a firm:
Alfred Marshall
1842-1924
From the perspective of society:
Rents may be price-determined (by demand-side)
Rents may be price-determining (part of costs)
Alfred Marshall
1842-1924
“[I]t is wisest not to say that ‘Rent does not enter into cost of production’: for that will confuse many people. But it is wicked to say ‘Rent does enter into cost of production,’ because that is sure to be applied in such a way as to lead to the denial of subtle truths.” — Letter to Francis Edgeworth
Alfred Marshall
1842-1924
In the short run (or market period), when supply of any particular factor is inelastic, changes in demand may cause above-normal returns
“Quasi-rents” paid to fixed factor in short run
“And thus even the rent of land is seen, not as a thing by itself, but as the leading species of a large genus.”
If firms earn profit in short-run...
More capital will flow into firm over long run, pushing profits to 0
If firms earn losses in short-run...
Capital will flow out of firm over long run in pursuit of normal profits, pushing losses to 0
Competitive industry in the long run: firms earn “normal profit”
Firms earn normal profits, the opportunity cost of holding capital in firm (versus other investment opportunities)
But in short run, when some factors are fixed (i.e. capital), if price \(>\) average cost:
Firm must pay its variable factors (variable costs) or else they will leave the firm
Revenues leftover go to fixed factors (fixed costs) i.e. K
“[I]n a sense all rents are scarcity rents, and all rents are differential rent.”
We often assume in neoclassical economics that capital is fixed in the short run
But Marshall’s quasi-rents can apply to any factor that is fixed in the short run!
Economies of scale come in two flavors:
Internal economies: firm-level features that improve a firm's productivity, often leading to market power for that firm
External economies: industry-wide features that spill over to the productivity all firms in the industry
Minimum Efficient Scale: \(q\) with the lowest \(AC(q)\)
Economies of Scale: \(\uparrow q\), \(\downarrow AC(q)\)
Minimum Efficient Scale: \(q\) with the lowest \(AC(q)\)
Economies of Scale: \(\uparrow q\), \(\downarrow AC(q)\)
Diseconomies of Scale: \(\uparrow q\), \(\uparrow AC(q)\)
Recall: economies of scale: as \(\uparrow q\), \(\downarrow AC(q)\)
Minimum Efficient Scale (MES): \(q\) with the lowest \(AC(q)\)
If MES is small relative to market demand...
Recall: economies of scale: as \(\uparrow q\), \(\downarrow AC(q)\)
Minimum Efficient Scale (MES): \(q\) with the lowest \(AC(q)\)
If MES is small relative to market demand...
If MES is large relative to market demand...
A natural monopoly that can produce higher \(q^*\) and lower \(p^*\) than a competitive industry!
When all firms produce more/less; or firms enter or exit an industry, this affects the equilibrium market price
Think about basic supply & demand graphs:
If the size of the entire industry affects all individual firm’s costs, then there are external economies effects
Constant cost industry has no external economies, no change in costs as industry output increases (firms enter & incumbents produce more)
A perfectly elastic long-run industry supply curve!
Determinants:
Examples: toothpicks, domain name registration, waitstaff
Industry equilibrium: firms earning normal \(\pi=0, p=MC(q)=AC(q)\)
Exogenous increase in market demand
Short run \((A \rightarrow B)\): industry reaches new equilibrium
Firms charge higher \(p^*\), produce more \(q^*\), earn \(\pi\)
Long run \((B \rightarrow C)\): profit attracts entry \(\implies\) industry supply increases
No change in costs to firms in industry, firms enter until \(\pi=0\) at \(p=AC(q)\)
Firms must charge original \(p^*\), return to original \(q^*\), earn \(\pi=0\)
Increasing cost industry has external diseconomies, costs rise for all firms in the industry as industry output increases (firms enter & incumbents produce more)
An upward sloping long-run industry supply curve!
Determinants:
Examples: oil, mining, particle physics
Industry equilibrium: firms earning normal \(\pi=0, p=MC(q)=AC(q)\)
Exogenous increase in market demand
Short run \((A \rightarrow B)\): industry reaches new equilibrium
Firms charge higher \(p^*\), produce more \(q^*\), earn \(\pi\)
Long run: profit attracts entry \(\implies\) industry supply will increase
But more production increases costs \((MC, AC)\) for all firms in industry
Long run \((B \rightarrow C)\): firms enter until \(\pi=0\) at \(p=AC(q)\)
Firms charge higher \(p^*\), producer lower \(q^*\), earn \(\pi=0\)
Decreasing cost industry has external economies, costs fall for all firms in the industry as industry output increases (firms enter & incumbents produce more)
A downward sloping long-run industry supply curve!
Determinants:
Examples: geographic clusters, public utilities, infrastructure, entertainment
Tends towards "natural" monopoly
Industry equilibrium: firms earning normal \(\pi=0, p=MC(q)=AC(q)\)
Exogenous increase in market demand
Short run \((A \rightarrow B)\): industry reaches new equilibrium
Firms charge higher \(p^*\), produce more \(q^*\), earn \(\pi\)
Long run: profit attracts entry \(\implies\) industry supply will increase
But more production lowers costs \((MC, AC)\) for all firms in industry
Long run \((B \rightarrow C)\): firms enter until \(\pi=0\) at \(p=AC(q)\)
Firms charge higher \(p^*\), producer lower \(q^*\), earn \(\pi=0\)
Alfred Marshall
1842-1924
“[G]reat are the advantages which people following the same trade get from near neighborhood...The mysteries of the trade become no mysteries; but are as it were in the air, and children learn many of them unconsciously. Good work is rightly appreciated, inventions and improvement in machinery, in process and the general organization of the business have their merits promptly discussed: if one man starts a new idea, it is taken up by others and combined with suggestions of their own; and thus it becomes the source of further new ideas.”
Marshall, Alfred, 1890, Principles of Economics, Ch. 10
Alfred Marshall
1842-1924
“...are dependent on the resources of individual houses of business engaged in [the industry], on their organization and the efficiency of their management,” (p.220).
“...are dependent on the general development of the industry [some of which] depend on the aggregate volume of production of the kind in the neighborhood while others again, especially those connected with the growth of knowledge and the progress of the arts, depend chiefly on the aggregate volume of production in the whole civilized world,” (p.220).
Alfred Marshall
1842-1924
“The most important of these result from the growth of correlated branches of industry which mutually assist one another, perhaps being concentrated in the same localities, but anyhow availing themselves of the modern facilities for communication offered by steam transport, by the telegraph and by the printing press,” (p.264).
Marshall, Alfred, 1890, Principles of Economics
150 Firms in Dalton, Georgia (pop. 33,000) supply over 70% of entire world’s carpet. Carpet has been made there since 1895.
990 firms in Hangji China (pop. 36,000) produce 3 billion toothbrushes a year, 80% of Chinese toothbrush production. Toothbrushes have been made there since 1827.
“[In Silicon Valley] engineers left established semiconductor companies to start firms that manufactured capital goods such as diffusion ovens, step-and-repeat cameras, and testers, and materials and components such as photomasks, testing jigs, and specialized chemicals. . . . This independent equipment sector promoted the continuing formation of semiconductor firms by freeing individual producers from the expense of developing capital equipment internally and by spreading the costs of development. It also reinforced the tendency toward industrial localization, as most of these specialized inputs were not available elsewhere in the country.”
“[In Silicon Valley] engineers left established semiconductor companies to start firms that manufactured capital goods such as diffusion ovens, step-and-repeat cameras, and testers, and materials and components such as photomasks, testing jigs, and specialized chemicals. . . . This independent equipment sector promoted the continuing formation of semiconductor firms by freeing individual producers from the expense of developing capital equipment internally and by spreading the costs of development. It also reinforced the tendency toward industrial localization, as most of these specialized inputs were not available elsewhere in the country.”
“it wasn’t that big a catastrophe to quit your job on Friday and have another job on Monday. . . . You didn’t even necessarily have to tell your wife. You just drove off in another direction on Monday morning”
Saxenian, Annalee, 1994, Regional Advantage. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, p.40
Adam Smith's pin factory illustration
Adam Smith
1723-1790
"As it is the power of exchanging that gives occasion to the division of labour, so the extent of this division must always be limited by...the extent of the market. When the market is very small, no person can have any encouragement to dedicate himself entirely to one employment, for want of the power to exchange all that surplus part of the produce of his own labour, which is over and above his own consumption, for such parts of the produce of other men's labour as he has occasion for," (Book I, Chapter 3).
Smith, Adam, 1776, An Enquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations
Economies of scale are inconsistent with perfect competition!
A problem that will be developed in 1920s-1930s
Joan Robinson
1903-1983
“Marshall had the ability to recognize hard problems and hide them in plain sight.”
Marshall thought that it might be a good idea (he showed geometrically) to tax industries with increasing costs (they produce less and lower prices) and subsidize industries with decreasing costs and this would on net improve consumer welfare
Other economists in other contexts, such as international trade, make similar proposals in early 20th century
Marshall doesn't quite give us a supply curve
But defines producer surplus in Appendix H
Once we consider producer surplus in economic welfare changes, Marshall's tax-bounty claim loses value
But over the long run, rents become capitalized into opportunity costs...
What do long run cost curves look like?
Source: From my ECON 306 slides
Keyboard shortcuts
↑, ←, Pg Up, k | Go to previous slide |
↓, →, Pg Dn, Space, j | Go to next slide |
Home | Go to first slide |
End | Go to last slide |
Number + Return | Go to specific slide |
b / m / f | Toggle blackout / mirrored / fullscreen mode |
c | Clone slideshow |
p | Toggle presenter mode |
t | Restart the presentation timer |
?, h | Toggle this help |
Esc | Back to slideshow |